“Shareholder Value” Isn’t What You Think It Is

David Grace
David Grace Columns Organized By Topic
5 min readDec 13, 2014

--

David Grace (DavidGraceAuthor.com)

When asked why a new fee is being levied or a plant is being closed or employees are been switched from full to part time we often hear the CEO’s explanation for the decision as, “I have an obligation to cut costs in order to increase shareholder value.”

This justification is based on several assumptions, namely:

  • All shareholders are the same and they all have the same definition of “Shareholder Value”;
  • The terms “shareholder value” and “stock price” mean the same thing
  • The time frame for determining whether an action increases or decreases shareholder value is twelve months or less.

All of these assumptions are false.

Every decision we make, either in business or in our personal lives, is grounded in the time frame the decider picked in making the analysis.

Every cost/benefit analysis measures anticipated costs and anticipated returns over a specific period of time. Sometimes the time frame is naturally very short.

“Should I fill the car with gas now?” has a cost/benefit analysis time frame that is inherently forty-eight hours or less. But, for many decisions the choice of time frame is wide open.

When executives at GM were making their cost/benefit analysis about whether or not to recall and replace their existing ignition switches with a new design a cost/benefit analysis with a one-year time frame resulted in a “No.”

If that cost/benefit analysis had used a ten-year time frame the answer would likely have been “Yes.”

When an executive asks “Will doing X increase shareholder value?” he leaves unexpressed the rest of the question: “Will doing X increase shareholder value over a time frame of [3 months; 12 months; 3 years; 7 years]?”

The answer he gets to that question will be different depending on the time frame he uses and that selected time frame depends on which group of shareholders he’s thinking about.

The shareholders of a public company are not a homogeneous group but rather are a mix of different shareholder subgroups who measure shareholder value differently.

These subgroups consist of, at least, the following:

  • Founders, employees and VCs who bought their stock directly from the company and intend to hold their stock for the long term (5 years or more)
  • Investors who bought stock at or after the public offering and intend to hold their stock for the long term
  • Institutional investors and other members of the public who bought the stock at or after the IPO and intend to hold their stock for the medium term (2–3 years)
  • Purchasers who intend to sell the stock in the short term (1 year or less)

The first and second groups are very interested in increasing the asset value of the company over a period of five or more years.

The third group is interested in increasing the stock price over a period of perhaps three years.

The fourth group is interested in increasing the stock price over a period of twelve months or less, often much less.

Of course, these groups can be divided into even smaller subgroups.

In group four traders and hedge-fund stockholders are interested in seeing an increase in the stock price over a period of weeks or days, the quicker the better because if a stock goes from 100 to 110 in a year then a sale gives the investor an annualized return of 10%. If the stock goes from 100 to 110 in five weeks then a sale gives the investor an annualized return of 100%.

A management decision to cut customer support, cut warranties, cut R&D and cut quality can massively increase the company’s bottom line in the short term. That increased profit can drive the up the stock price over the short term and greatly increase what group four thinks of as “shareholder value” namely an increase in the stock price.

Over a five-year time frame it will also likely decrease the company’s net asset value and stock price and thus decrease shareholder value for groups one, two and three. Consider Hewlett Packard.

When you recognize that shareholder value is time related and that it means different things to different groups of shareholders the CEO’s statement, “I did it to increase shareholder value” demands the followup questions: “Which shareholders?” and “Over what time frame?”

I will propose a radically different way of dealing with these issues:

What if everyone who bought their shares directly from the company, either as founder’s stock, pre-IPO purchases, via employee stock-option exercises or IPO purchases had voting rights in those shares, and everyone who purchased shares on an exchange from a seller other than the issuer received shares without voting rights?

I buy 100,000 shares from the issuer in the IPO. I can vote those shares. I sell those shares to you via the stock exchange. The company’s Articles provide that upon that sale all voting rights in those shares terminate.

This would mean that the voting shareholders would be limited to those who had actually paid money into the company, who had “skin in the game,” who had invested their money in the company itself versus those who risked their money on the gamble that the stock price would go up.

As an aside, shares sold by one voting shareholder to another voting shareholder would retain their voting rights.

Perhaps the governance documents could provide that those who held their nonvoting shares for X years or more (3 years?) would get voting rights at the end of that Voting Rights Holding Period.

How about vesting voting rights over time? After 3 years you get to vote 25% of your shares. After 4 years, 50% and so forth so that people who buy stock from a seller other than the issuer will fully vest their voting rights in those shares after a six-year holding period?

A rule like this would still let the hedge funds and the traders buy and sell stock in the Wall Street Casino. They could still use the stock as a gambling vehicle, but the governance of the company would be limited to those who had actually given money to the company itself or at least had demonstrated a commitment to the company’s profitability over the long term.

I think that such a rule would help weaken the implied equivalence of the terms “shareholder value” and “today’s trading price” so that when a CEO talked about increasing shareholder value we would know that he was not necessarily talking about simply increasing this year’s bottom line in order to benefit the gamblers in the Wall Street Casino who had never directly paid a single penny into the company’s coffers.

While we’re at it, what if the bylaws provided that no one could be a director unless he/she owned voting stock equal to the lesser of (a) $1M dollars or (b) 1% of the company’s outstanding voting shares?

Of course, directors could always meet with outside consultants or advisers to help them understand complex issues, but the actual director’s vote would be in the hands of someone, again, who had skin in the game.

What kind of company would Hewlett Packard be today if those shareholder-voting rules and board of directors membership rules had been in place for HP? This is not a rhetorical question. Seriously, what do you think? Would those changes have had a good, bad or indifferent effect?

What is the purpose of this post?

To get people to think creatively or at least differently about issues of corporate governance and about structural methods that might be used to encourage a shift from short term to long term corporate decision making.

David Grace (DavidGraceAuthor.com

To see a searchable list of all David Grace’s columns in chronological order, CLICK HERE

To see a list of David Grace’s columns sorted by topic/subject matter, CLICK HERE.

--

--

David Grace
David Grace Columns Organized By Topic

Graduate of Stanford University & U.C. Berkeley Law School. Author of 16 novels and over 400 Medium columns on Economics, Politics, Law, Humor & Satire.