Labor, Capital and Adoption

Or, how to unlock network effects by explicitly rewarding early adopters with discount tokens

Julien Genestoux
5 min readMay 25, 2018

First, a quick warning: I am not an economist, not an historian. I make a bunch of simplifications and approximations: please correct me when I am flat out wrong!

Capital vs. Labor

The 18th and 19th century saw the emergence of the capital/labor duality. In order to produce industrially, factories need to be built, and workers need to be hired. Since then, economists and politicians have fought hard to agree on ways to pay each of these two essentials participants. At this point, it seems fairly agreed upon that workers are paid “consistently”, but moderately, while capitalists take on variance: they may not be paid, but if (or when) they do, they get most of the upside.

Supply, demand and price

Later, the market economy theory introduced another paradigm to reason about pricing: supply vs. demand. Both of these will converge toward some kind of equilibrium, determining the prices of goods and services. The direct consequence is that prices are not just determined by production costs, but also by the value created (or perceived) on the demand side.

Economies of scale

Since the producers only have a partial role to set the prices, producers had to focus on reducing the production costs. To do that, some of them have focused their efforts on economies of scale. Reducing production costs only has benefits: if prices remain stable, profits increased, and if prices decline, the competition intensifies, ejecting competitors who did not reach the required scale.

It is interesting to note that economies of scales are often the result of large capital investments and the resulting profits (or losses) are then captured by capitalists more than workers.

Network effects

The emergence of modern communication tools also introduced the concept of network effects, which is the mirror of economies of scale on the demand side: the value of a product or service for its consumers increases with its usage (vs. decreasing production costs with volume). Since the value for the consumer increases, in theory, this means that prices could increase too… but, as production costs (labor and capital) are not increasing, competing producers have a hard time driving prices up.

In the same way that economies of scale can be triggered by rewarding those who invest to decrease production costs, I believe network effects can be triggered by rewarding consumers whose usage of a product or service increases its value for others. This reward can take the form of a discount token.

Discount tokens are dividends for consumers’ “adoption”

Let’s take the simplistic example of the fax machine network. For those born after y2k, a fax is like an email, but through a telephone line. For the sake of this example, let’s assume a fax machine costs $100 and it is required to send messages to one another.

Fax machines are using telephone lines. Photo by Pavan Trikutam on Unsplash

Of course, a single fax machine is pointless (as you cannot even send faxes to yourself, since the fax protocol is “sync”). The 2nd fax machine is already more useful because it means the 2 users can now exchange messages with one another… The network’s value is directly related to its ability to “connect” people. Since everyone can be connected with everyone, Metcalfe’s law applies: the value of the fax network is the square of its number of participants.

Now, buying a fax machine when everybody else has one is not a very bold move, while buying the first one of your group of contacts is a pretty significant one, because the machine will only be useful if more members of the group get one too.

One could argue that economies of scale actually work against early adopters: they take more risks (what if no one else buys a fax machine?) and end up paying more than the people who join later: the more fax machines are produced, the cheaper they become because the producers’ investments are amortized over more machines. How can we reverse that and increase the reward for early adopters if the network eventually grows?

Enter discount tokens!

Let’s say each purchaser of a fax machine receives points to get discounts on more fax machines, at the time of the purchase. They can keep their points, and use or sell them to people who want to purchase fax machines at any time. The number of points they get is based on how early they purchased their fax machine. For example, let’s assume that the number of points someone gets is 100k/number of sold fax machines^2. The first person gets 100k points, the 2nd gets 25k, the 3rd gets 11k… etc. Why do we use the ^2? Because of Metcalfe’s law: we know that the network’s value grows as the square of fax machine sold: so the value each participant receives should decrease similarly.

On the other end, the amount of discount each point yields is also based on the amount of sold fax machines: let’s take 1 point is 0.01ct * number of previously sold fax machines. If they used their points right away, the first user would then be able to get 100,000 * 1 / 100 * 1/100 = $10 in discount on their second fax machine. However, if the 1st buyer “waited” for 1,000 machines to have been sold, their 100,000 points would actually be worth $10,000 (100,000 * 1 / 100 * 1/100 * 1000) in discounts.

Similarly, the 1,000th person to join the network only receives 0.1 point, worth $0.01 if they used it right away… or $10 is they waited for the network to have 1M participants.

This model incentivizes people to become early participants in the fax machines network. If they do, and if the network eventually becomes large, they are rewarded for their initial “bet”. However, if somebody purchases a fax machine when tens of thousands of people have done so before, they do not see much of the benefits.

It is pretty clear now that this scheme is very (maybe too much) lucrative for early adopters. What is interesting is that the cost for the manufacturer is capped because the sum of 1/n² converges to π²/6 , so there will always be less than 164,493 points outstanding. Similarly, the “value” of a point is based on the number of machines previously sold. This means that the value of each point only increases if the network’s size increases. In practice, at any time, the the manufacturer will only ever spend at most 16.4% of their revenues in discounts.

We could of course improve this token design to make it slightly less rewarding for the very first users but also more valuable for the 1,000th person and further, based on a threshold after which the network effects are enough for people to become members of the network without any additional reward.

We often rightfully tout blockchains as ways to reward protocol and open source developers, or miners who provide a service for the network… But it is also important to understand that the token economics can go far beyond and reward actual users of the network themselves.

--

--