Game Theory and Tokenomics

Umar Sharomi
21 min readFeb 2, 2023

--

Definition of Game Theory

Game theory is the study of mathematical models of strategic interaction between rational decision-makers. It has applications in all fields of social science, as well as in logic, systems science and computer science. Game theory tries to mathematically capture behaviour in strategic situations, in which an individual’s success in making choices depends on the choices of others.

In game theory, the participants are often referred to as "players". They make choices simultaneously or sequentially, and each player’s choice directly affects the outcome of the game. The goal of game theory is to find a solution concept that predicts how rational players will behave in these interactions.

The most famous solution concept in game theory is the Nash equilibrium, named after Nobel Prize-winning economist John Nash.

Game theory is a tool used to understand and analyze interactions between rational decision-makers, and to predict their behaviour in various situations. The situations analysed in game theory are called "games" and can take many forms, including two-person games, multi-person games, and even games played between individuals and organizations. The decisions made by each player in a game affect not only their own outcome, but also the outcomes of the other players.



In game theory, each player is assumed to act rationally and make decisions that are in their best interest. The players have different objectives, which can conflict with each other. The outcome of the game depends on the choices made by all players, and game theory tries to find a way to predict what these choices will be.

The Nash equilibrium is a key concept in game theory and refers to a situation where each player’s strategy is the best response to the strategies of the other players. In other words, no player has an incentive to change their strategy, given the strategies of the other players. The Nash equilibrium is considered a stable solution, as no player has an incentive to change their strategy once the game has started.

Game theory is widely used in many fields, including economics, political science, psychology, and biology, to analyze and understand interactions between individuals and organizations. It has also been used to study issues such as market competition, international relations, and even the evolution of species.



Brief History of Game Theory

Game theory has its roots in the works of several economists and mathematicians in the early 20th century. However, the development of game theory as a formal discipline can be traced back to the 1944 publication of John von Neumann and Oskar Morgenstern’s book "Theory of Games and Economic Behaviour ."

In this book, von Neumann and Morgenstern introduced the idea of using mathematical models to study decision-making in strategic situations. They showed how game theory could be used to analyze economic interactions, and introduced the concept of the Nash equilibrium.

After the publication of this book, game theory quickly gained recognition as a valuable tool for understanding strategic decision-making. It was applied to a wide range of fields, including economics, political science, psychology, and biology.



In the 1950s and 1960s, game theory was further developed by mathematicians and economists, including John Nash, Kenneth Arrow, and Lloyd Shapitan. During this time, the field expanded to include the study of dynamic games, cooperative games, and non-cooperative games.

In 1994, John Nash was awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics for his contributions to game theory. Since then, game theory has continued to be an active area of research, and its applications have expanded to include topics such as network theory, artificial intelligence, and computer science.



Importance of Game Theory in Various Fields

Game theory has a wide range of applications in various fields, including:

Economics: Game theory provides a tool for understanding the behaviour of firms and consumers in markets. For example, it can be used to analyze how firms will respond to changes in prices or the introduction of new products. It can also be used to study oligopolies, in which a few firms dominate a market, and to understand how firms interact with each other in such markets. Game theory has also been used to study auction design, bargaining, and price discrimination.



Political Science: Game theory has important applications in political science, particularly in the study of voting behaviour , bargaining, and conflict resolution. For example, it can be used to understand how voters make decisions in elections, how political parties bargain with each other to form coalitions, and how conflicts between nations can be resolved.



Psychology: Game theory is used in psychology to study social preferences, cooperation, and conflict. For example, it can be used to understand why people cooperate in some situations and compete in others, as well as to study the behaviour of groups and organizations.



Biology: Game theory has applications in biology, particularly in the study of evolution, behaviour of animals, and populations. For example, it can be used to understand how populations of animals evolve over time and how the behaviour of individuals affects the survival and reproduction of their species.



Management Science: Game theory is used in management science to study decision-making in firms, as well as in supply chain management and resource allocation. For example, it can be used to understand how firms make decisions about production and pricing, and how they allocate resources to different projects.



Computer Science: Game theory is used in computer science to study algorithms, artificial intelligence, and network design. For example, it can be used to design algorithms that make decisions based on the behaviour of other agents in a network, and to understand the behaviour of artificial intelligence systems.



Law: Game theory has applications in law, particularly in the study of legal settlements, contracts, and negotiations. For example, it can be used to understand how parties in a legal dispute make decisions about settlement, and how contracts are formed and enforced.

In each of these fields, game theory provides a systematic and mathematical framework for understanding and analyzing strategic decision-making, and has proven to be a valuable tool for researchers and practitioners alike



Basic Concepts of Game Theory

  1. Games and Strategies

    In game theory, a game is a situation in which two or more individuals, called “Players”, make decisions that affect each other’s outcomes. The players in a game have a set of available actions, or strategies, and their choice of strategy determines the outcome of the game.

    A strategy is a complete plan of action that specifies what a player will do in all possible circumstances. For example, in a two-player game, a strategy for one player might specify what they will do if their opponent chooses strategy A, what they will do if their opponent chooses strategy B, and so on.

    In game theory, the focus is on analyzing the interplay between players' strategies and the outcomes of the game. The goal is to understand how players make decisions and how their decisions impact each other. To do this, game theorists use mathematical models to analyze the behaviour of players and predict the outcomes of different games.
  2. Nash Equilibrium

    The Nash Equilibrium is a fundamental concept in game theory named after John Nash, the Nobel Prize-winning mathematician who first described it. It is a solution concept for non-cooperative games, where players do not form coalitions and cannot make binding agreements.

    In a Nash Equilibrium, each player chooses a strategy that is the best response to the strategies chosen by the other players. That is, no player can unilaterally change their strategy and improve their outcome. In other words, a Nash Equilibrium is a set of strategies, one for each player, such that no player has an incentive to change their strategy given the strategies of the other players.

    Formally, a Nash Equilibrium is defined as a set of strategies, one for each player, such that for each player i, their strategy is a best response to the strategies of the other players, given by j ≠ i. That is, for each player i, their strategy maximizes their payoff given the strategies of the other players.

    The Nash Equilibrium is an important concept in game theory because it provides a prediction of how players will behave in a non-cooperative game. It is widely used in economics, political science, psychology, and many other fields to analyze and understand the behaviour of individuals and groups in strategic situations.

    It is important to note that a Nash Equilibrium is not necessarily unique, and that there may be multiple Nash Equilibria in a game. In some cases, the Nash Equilibrium may not exist, or it may be that no player has a dominant strategy. In such cases, other solution concepts, such as the Correlated Equilibrium or the Evolutionarily Stable Strategy, may be used to analyze the game.
  3. Dominant Strategy

    A dominant strategy is a strategy that is the best choice for a player, regardless of the strategies chosen by the other players. In other words, a dominant strategy is a strategy that gives the player the highest payoff, no matter what the other players do. A player with a dominant strategy will always choose that strategy, regardless of the strategies chosen by the other players. This makes dominant strategies a very strong prediction of behaviour in game theory. If all players in a game have a dominant strategy, the game is said to have a dominant strategy equilibrium. This means that each player’s best strategy is the same, regardless of what the other players do.

    It is important to note that not all games have a dominant strategy. In many games, players must consider the strategies of the other players in order to determine their best strategy. In such cases, the Nash Equilibrium may provide a better prediction of behaviour .
  4. Correlated Equilibrium

    In a Correlated Equilibrium, the players' strategies are correlated, meaning that their strategies are not chosen independently, but are instead chosen based on a common signal or information. The Correlated Equilibrium is a generalization of the Nash Equilibrium and can be used to analyze games where players have incomplete information or where players' strategies are not independent.
  5. Evolutionarily Stable Strategy (ESS)

    In an Evolutionarily Stable Strategy, a strategy is considered to be stable if it is the best response to itself. That is, if all players in a population adopt a particular strategy, it is the best response for each player to continue to use that strategy, even in the presence of mutations or deviations. The ESS is used to analyze games where players' strategies evolve over time, such as in biological or cultural evolution.
  6. Pareto Efficiency

    Pareto Efficiency is a solution concept in game theory that is used to determine if a game has a fair and efficient outcome. A game is said to be Pareto Efficient if there is no way to make any player better off without making another player worse off. Pareto Efficiency is used to analyze the fairness and efficiency of outcomes in cooperative games, where players can form coalitions and make binding agreements.

Minimax

The Minimax is a solution concept that is used to analyze two-player, zero-sum games. In a zero-sum game, one player’s gain is exactly equal to the other player’s loss. The Minimax is the strategy that minimizes the maximum possible loss for a player, given the strategies of the other player. The Minimax is used to analyze games where one player is trying to minimize their maximum possible loss, and the other player is trying to maximize their minimum possible gain.

These are just a few of the solution concepts used in game theory to analyze the behaviour of players in strategic situations. Each concept provides a different perspective on how players make decisions and how their decisions impact each other, and each is useful for analyzing different types of games and strategic situations.





Types of Games in Game Theory

In game theory, there are several types of games that are used to model and analyze different types of strategic situations. Some of the most common types of games include:

Zero-sum games: A zero-sum game is a type of game where one player’s gain is exactly equal to the other player’s loss. In other words, the total amount of payoff in the game is constant, and any gain by one player must be offset by an equal loss by the other player. Examples of zero-sum games include chess and poker.

Non-zero-sum games: A non-zero-sum game is a type of game where the total amount of payoff in the game is not constant and one player’s gain does not necessarily have to be offset by an equal loss by the other player. Examples of non-zero-sum games include cooperation and coordination games, where players can benefit from working together.

Cooperative games: Cooperative games are a type of non-zero-sum game where players can form coalitions and make binding agreements. In a cooperative game, the players can increase their combined payoffs by working together, as opposed to acting independently. Examples of cooperative games include the prisoner’s dilemma and the stag hunt.

Non-cooperative games: Non-cooperative games are a type of non-zero-sum game where players do not have the ability to form coalitions or make binding agreements. In a non-cooperative game, each player must choose their own strategy independently, without considering the strategies of the other players. Examples of non-cooperative games include the prisoner’s dilemma and the ultimatum game.

Simultaneous games: Simultaneous games are games where all players choose their strategies at the same time, without knowing the strategies chosen by the other players. In a simultaneous game, players must make their decisions based on their own best guess of what the other players will do. Examples of simultaneous games include the prisoner’s dilemma and the battle of the sexes.

Sequential games: Sequential games are games where players take turns making their decisions. In a sequential game, players can take into account the decisions made by the other players in previous rounds when making their own decisions. Examples of sequential games include the iterated prisoner’s dilemma and the game of chicken.

Cooperative and Non-Cooperative Games: In game theory, cooperative games are a type of non-zero-sum game where players can form coalitions and make binding agreements. In a cooperative game, players can increase their combined payoffs by working together, as opposed to acting independently. In contrast, non-cooperative games are a type of non-zero-sum game where players do not have the ability to form coalitions or make binding agreements. In a non-cooperative game, each player must choose their own strategy independently, without considering the strategies of the other players.

Static and Dynamic Games: Static games are games where the number of players and the strategies available to each player are fixed throughout the game. In a static game, players make their decisions simultaneously, without knowing the strategies chosen by the other players. Dynamic games, on the other hand, are games where the number of players and the strategies available to each player can change over time. In a dynamic game, players make their decisions sequentially, taking into account the decisions made by the other players in previous rounds.

Normal and Extensive Form Games: Normal form games are a type of static game where the players and their strategies are presented in a matrix. In a normal form game, each row represents the strategies available to one player, and each column represents the strategies available to all other players. The entries in the matrix represent the payoffs for each combination of strategies. In contrast, extensive form games are a type of dynamic game where the game is represented as a tree, with each node representing a decision point and each branch representing a possible outcome. In an extensive form game, players make their decisions sequentially, and their choices at each decision point determine the available options at future decision points

These are just a few of the types of games used in game theory to model and analyze different types of strategic situations. Each type of game has its own unique characteristics, and each is useful for analyzing different types of decision-making situations.

Subfields of Game Theory

Coperative Game theory: Studies games in which players can form coalitions and make binding agreements. It focuses on the division of the total payoff among the players and the conditions under which cooperation is possible. The core solution concepts in cooperative game theory are the core and the Shapley value.

Non-cooperative Game Theory: Studies games in which players act independently and cannot make binding agreements. It focuses on the strategies that players choose and the resulting outcomes. The core solution concepts in non-cooperative game theory are Nash equilibrium and Dominant strategy.

Evolutionary Game Theory: Studies how the behaviour of individuals and populations evolves over time in response to changes in the environment and interactions with other individuals. It uses mathematical models to study the evolution of strategies in populations of individuals. The core solution concepts in evolutionary game theory are Evolutionarily Stable Strategies (ESS) and Replicator Dynamics.

Repeated Games: Studies games that are played multiple times, either between the same players or between different players. It focuses on the impact of the history of play on the current and future behaviour of players. The core solution concepts in repeated games are Trigger Strategies and Tit-for-Tat.

Dynamic Games: Studies games in which the rules and payoffs can change over time. It focuses on the interaction between players over time and the resulting outcomes. The core solution concepts in dynamic games are Stackelberg Equilibrium and Subgame Perfect Equilibrium.

Mechanism Design Theory: Studies how to design mechanisms, such as auctions and voting systems, to achieve desirable outcomes. It focuses on the design of institutions that align the incentives of individuals with the goals of society. The core solution concepts in mechanism design theory are Incentive Compatibility and Revelation Principle.

Social Choice Theory: Studies how to aggregate individual preferences into collective decisions, such as electing a government or choosing a collective good. It focuses on the aggregation of individual preferences into a collective decision, taking into account the incentives and motivations of individuals. The core solution concepts in social choice theory are Arrow’s Impossibility Theorem and Gibbard-Satterthwaite Theorem.



Bounded Rationality in Game Theory

Bounded rationality is a concept in economics and decision theory that suggests that people and organizations make decisions based on limited information, computational abilities, and time. It assumes that decision-makers are not perfectly rational, but instead, make decisions based on heuristics, biases, and other cognitive limitations.

The concept of bounded rationality is important because it acknowledges that decision-makers are not always able to gather and process all relevant information, and are subject to biases and other cognitive limitations. By recognizing these limitations, researchers and practitioners can better understand how people and organizations make decisions and design more effective decision-making processes and tools.

In addition, the concept of bounded rationality has been used to develop alternative models of decision-making, such as heuristics and prospect theory, that take into account the limitations and biases of decision-makers. These models have been used to explain a wide range of real-world phenomena, such as risk-taking behaviour , decision-making under uncertainty, and consumer behaviour .

Limitations of Human Decision-Making

There are several limitations of human decision-making that can impact the quality and accuracy of decisions. Some of these limitations include:

Cognitive Biases: People are often influenced by various cognitive biases, such as confirmation bias, framing effects, and overconfidence bias, which can distort their perception of reality and lead to suboptimal decisions.

Limited Information Processing Capacity: People can only process a limited amount of information at a given time, which can lead to suboptimal decisions when faced with complex or overwhelming amounts of information.

Emotions And Intuition: Emotions and intuition can play a significant role in decision-making, leading people to prioritize short-term or emotional goals over long-term or rational goals.

Time Constraints: People are often limited by the amount of time available to make a decision, which can lead to decisions that are based on incomplete or insufficient information.

Social And Cultural Influences: People are often influenced by social and cultural norms, as well as group dynamics, which can impact the way they make decisions and the decisions they make.

Incentives And Motivation: People’s incentives and motivations can impact their decision-making, leading them to prioritize self-interest over the greater good.

Unforeseen Events And Uncertainty: People are often unable to anticipate or account for unforeseen events or uncertain future outcomes, which can lead to suboptimal decisions.

These limitations can be exacerbated in organizations, where decisions are made by groups of people with varying motivations, incentives, and perspectives. Understanding these limitations is crucial for designing decision-making processes and systems that account for them and reduce their impact.

Implications for Game Theory

The limitations of human decision-making have important implications for game theory. Game theory assumes that decision-makers are rational and make decisions based on complete information, but the limitations of human decision-making suggest that this may not always be the case.

For example, cognitive biases and limited information processing capacity can impact how players perceive and understand the payoffs of different strategies, leading them to make suboptimal decisions. Social and cultural influences can impact the way players interact and cooperate with each other, affecting the outcome of the game. And emotions and intuition can lead players to prioritize short-term goals over long-term ones, impacting the overall stability of the game.

Additionally, the limitations of human decision-making can impact the applicability and validity of game theoretical models and solutions. For example, the Nash Equilibrium, which assumes that players are rational and have complete information, may not accurately reflect the decisions that players actually make in real-world scenarios.

To account for these limitations, researchers have developed alternative models of decision-making, such as bounded rationality, heuristics, and prospect theory, which take into account the limitations and biases of decision-makers. These models have been used to better understand real-world scenarios and develop more accurate predictions and solutions.



The Classic Prisoner’s Dilemma

Description of the Dilemma

The prisoner’s dilemma is a classic example of a game analyzed in game theory that shows why two completely rational individuals might not cooperate, even if it appears that it is in their best interest to do so.

The scenario is as follows: two suspects are arrested for a crime and are being held in separate cells. The police do not have enough evidence to convict the suspects, so they offer each suspect a deal. If one suspect confesses and the other stays silent, the confessing suspect will receive a lighter sentence, while the silent suspect will receive a harsher sentence. If both suspects confess, they will both receive a medium sentence. If both remain silent, they will both receive a light sentence.

The dilemma lies in the fact that each suspect has to make a decision without knowing the decision of the other suspect. If the suspects think that the other suspect will confess, it is in their best interest to confess as well, in order to receive the lighter sentence. However, if both suspects confess, they will both receive a medium sentence, which is worse than if they had both stayed silent.

This paradox highlights the conflict between individual rationality and collective rationality. Each suspect acts rationally based on their own self-interest, but the result is not the best outcome for either suspect or for society as a whole. The prisoner’s dilemma is used to model a wide range of situations, from the arms race between nations to the management of common resources.

Analysis of the Dilemma

The prisoner’s dilemma provides a mathematical framework for analyzing situations where two or more individuals must make a decision without knowing what the other is going to do. In terms of game theory, the prisoner’s dilemma is a non-cooperative game in which the best outcome for each player is not the best outcome for both players.

In the prisoner’s dilemma, each player must choose between two strategies: to confess or to remain silent. The payoffs for each player depend on both their own decision and the decision of the other player. If one player confesses and the other stays silent, the confessing player receives a payoff of T (temptation), while the silent player receives a payoff of S (sucker’s payoff). If both players confess, they both receive a payoff of P (punishment). If both players stay silent, they both receive a payoff of R (reward).

The Nash equilibrium of the prisoner’s dilemma is for both players to confess, even though this is not the optimal outcome for either player. This is because each player acts in their own self-interest and assumes that the other player will confess. This leads to a suboptimal outcome for both players, as they receive a payoff of P, which is worse than the reward they would receive if they both stayed silent.

The prisoner’s dilemma has important implications for decision-making in situations where cooperation is required, such as environmental conservation, international relations, and business. In many real-world situations, the temptation to act in one’s own self-interest can lead to negative outcomes for both the individual and society as a whole. In order to overcome the prisoner’s dilemma, it is necessary to find ways to incentivize cooperation, such as through the use of punishments, rewards, or agreements.

The prisoner’s dilemma is also an important concept in evolutionary game theory, as it provides a framework for understanding the evolution of cooperation in populations. Researchers have found that in some cases, cooperative behaviour can evolve in populations, even in the absence of any central authority or enforcement mechanism. This suggests that cooperation may be an evolutionarily stable strategy in some situations, and that the prisoner’s dilemma may not always lead to a suboptimal outcome.

Significance of the Dilemma

The prisoner’s dilemma is a significant concept in game theory and has wide-ranging implications for various fields. Some of the key significance of the dilemma include:

• Understanding Cooperative Behaviour : The prisoner’s dilemma provides a framework for analyzing situations where individuals face a trade-off between acting in their own self-interest and cooperating with others. By understanding the dynamics of the prisoner’s dilemma, researchers can gain insight into why individuals may or may not cooperate, and how to encourage cooperation in different situations.

International Relations: The prisoner’s dilemma is often used to analyze conflicts between nations. In international relations, the dilemma can help to explain why nations may engage in arms races or other aggressive behaviour , even though this behaviour is not in the best interest of either nation.

Environmental Conservation: The prisoner’s dilemma can also be applied to environmental issues, such as the tragedy of the commons, where individuals face a trade-off between exploiting a shared resource and conserving it for future generations.

• Business Strategy: In business, the prisoner’s dilemma can be used to analyze competition between firms, as well as to understand the incentives for cooperation and non-cooperation in supply chains and other business relationships.

Evolution of Cooperation: The prisoner’s dilemma is also a key concept in evolutionary game theory, as it provides a framework for understanding the evolution of cooperative behaviour in populations.

Overall, the prisoner’s dilemma has significant implications for a wide range of fields, and its importance lies in its ability to provide a simple but powerful framework for analyzing situations where individuals face a trade-off between cooperation and competition.



Relating Tokenomics

Mechanism design theory is a subfield of game theory that focuses on designing the rules and incentives for interactions between individuals and organizations in order to achieve desired outcomes. The goal of mechanism design is to ensure that the incentives of all participants are aligned with the goals of the system, so that everyone acts in a way that leads to a desirable outcome.

In the context of tokenomics, mechanism design theory can be applied to design the rules and incentives for token holders, developers, and users, in order to ensure that the network is secure, scalable, and efficient. For example, mechanism design can be used to design the consensus mechanism of a blockchain network, such as the proof-of-work (PoW) or proof-of-stake (PoS) mechanism, in order to ensure that the network is secure and decentralized.

Another example of the application of mechanism design in tokenomics is the design of token governance systems. Token governance systems are used to make decisions about the future development and direction of a token network, and they often involve voting by token holders. Mechanism design theory can be used to design the rules and incentives of these voting systems in order to ensure that the decisions made by the network are in the best interest of all participants.

In general, mechanism design theory is a valuable tool for understanding and designing token networks and decentralized systems more broadly, as it provides a framework for thinking about the incentives and behaviour of all participants in a system, and for designing rules and incentives that lead to desired outcomes.

One real-world example of the application of mechanism design in tokenomics is the Ethereum network, which uses a governance system based on mechanism design principles to make decisions about the future development of the network. Through its governance system, Ethereum allows token holders to propose and vote on changes to the network, and the rules of the governance system are designed to ensure that the incentives of all participants are aligned with the goals of the network



Conclusion

In conclusion, game theory is a branch of mathematics that studies decision-making in situations where individuals or organizations interact with each other. It provides a framework for understanding and predicting behaviour in a wide range of situations, including economic competition, political conflict, and cooperation in both human and non-human populations.

Some key concepts in game theory include Nash Equilibrium, dominant strategy, cooperative and non-cooperative games, static and dynamic games, and normal and extensive form games. Bounded rationality and the limitations of human decision-making also play a significant role in the study of game theory.

Game theory has many subfields, including cooperative game theory, evolutionary game theory, and mechanism design theory, each of which addresses specific questions and challenges within the broader field. One of the most famous examples in game theory is the prisoner’s dilemma, which highlights the trade-off between cooperation and competition in situations where individuals face conflicting interests. The prisoner’s dilemma has far-reaching implications for many fields, including international relations, environmental conservation, business strategy, and the evolution of cooperation.

Overall, game theory is a valuable tool for understanding and predicting behaviour in situations where individuals or organizations interact, and its insights have been widely applied in a variety of fields.

Future Outlook of Game Theory

The future outlook of game theory is promising as the field continues to grow and evolve, with new applications being developed and new insights being gained. Some of the key areas where game theory is likely to have a significant impact in the future include:

Artificial Intelligence and Machine Learning: As AI and machine learning become increasingly important in many fields, game theory is likely to play a key role in helping to understand and design intelligent systems that can interact with humans in a variety of settings.

  1. Blockchain and Decentralized Systems: Game theory has the potential to play a significant role in the design and analysis of decentralized systems, such as blockchain, where individuals and organizations interact in complex ways.
  2. Climate Change And Environmental Policy: Game theory can be applied to analyze the incentives and behaviour of individuals, organizations, and governments in addressing global challenges such as climate change.
  3. Healthcare: Game theory can be used to analyze the incentives and behaviour of healthcare providers, patients, and governments, and to design policies that promote more efficient and equitable healthcare systems.
  4. Cybersecurity: Game theory has the potential to play a role in the design and analysis of cybersecurity systems, helping to understand the incentives and behaviour of individuals and organizations in a complex and rapidly changing field.

--

--

Umar Sharomi

Blockchain Researcher | Writer || Tokenomics Analyst || Foreign Exchange Trader Cryptoeconomic Models