A market for social capital: The theory and application of Status as a Service

The definitive guide to Eugene Wei’s StaaS, including the playbook networks need to gain and sustain traction

Anthony Bardaro
Adventures in Consumer Technology
13 min readMar 6, 2019

--

👆choose GREEN to annotate this article or PINK to get a summary👆
Social currency

From academics to startups to conglomerates, Eugene Wei captured the business world’s attention last week with his almost 20k word thesis, “Status as a Service”, about network economics. Thanks to Annotote 🙏, I’m going to draw upon my own highlights and notes from Wei’s epic to draft off of him a bit — essentially summarizing his core tenets before tying it all back in to a usable strategic framework that entrepreneurs, business owners, and established executives can actually apply…

Recipe for traction

Once he got up to speed, Wei discussed the prerequisites for new social networks to bootstrap adoption:

As a newbie, how quickly, if you put in the work, are you ‘in the game’? [Upstart social networks] should track the ROI on posts for new users… test a social networks [sic] by posting varied content from test accounts to gauge the efficiency and fairness of the distribution algorithm… Whatever the mechanisms, social networks must devote a lot of resources to market making between content and the right audience for that content so that users feel sufficient return on their work…

Value is tied to scarcity, and scarcity on social networks derives from proof of work. Status isn’t worth much if there’s no skill and effort required to mine it [and, ultimately,] competition for relative status still motivates humans… What matters is less our absolute status than how are we doing compared to those around us…

In other words, Wei’s framework has two hooks that social networks need to gain traction…

  1. The curation algorithm must foster a meritocracy by rewarding quality, not an oligarchy by entrenching quantity:
    Not only because ‘quality is scarcity is value’ (self-reinforcing the macro network’s worth), but also because new users can join at any time and put in the work to earn their status (self-reinforcing the micro user’s access to social uplift). This allows the network to scale quality content and quality users, rather than entrench early adopters, whose tenure blocks the social mobility sought by mass market adopters. Overindexing to the latter — those grandfathered-in to high society thanks to legacy — can spark a downward spiral in quality, scarcity, and value.
  2. The network must provoke users with a competition for social status:
    People are motivated by their social status/social capital/social currency, so mere participation in a new network should feel like gaining admission into an exclusive club — surpassing a social filter like Facebook’s “powerful slingshots of elitism” mentioned below. Furthermore, competition among that club’s admitted members should further stratify them.

This two-part recipe sounds good and makes sense — common sense mixed with a dash of psychological anthropology. But, it’s easier said than done…

The scoreboard conundrum

Visible social leaderboard? (Black Mirror S3:E1 “Nosedive”)

First, those two hooks should raise an important question for network architects: Does a network that obfuscates its measure of social status — by burying it in a back-end algorithm rather than displaying it in a front-end league table — send a strong enough signal to satisfy a user’s humblebrag? Or do users want something more visible — like a public-facing scoreboard — to give them tangible, quantifiable street cred?

Wei actually implies that more discreet measures like Facebook’s News Feed algorithm can be sufficient to trigger the desired competition, because humans’ innate drive toward social status-seeking makes them root-out the means to virality on every new platform — even if the score is somewhat opaque:

[Facebook’s] News Feed unleashed a gold rush for social capital accumulation. Wow, that post over there has ten times the likes that my latest does! Okay, what can I learn from it to use in my next post? Which of my content is driving the most likes? We talk about the miracles of machine learning in the modern age, but as social creatures, humans are no less remarkable in their ability to decipher and internalize what plays well to the peanut gallery. [But,] the tighter the feedback loop, the quicker the adaptation.

In the end there, Wei essentially says that ‘the more visible the social capital, the better’ for scaling a network, but he later adds the caveat that sustainable networks are built on the back of the utility axis, as opposed to the social capital axis, of a network’s 2x2 matrix. In other words, utility is hard to create, but it’s longer-lasting and impossible to overserve; in contrast, social status is easy to game, but it’s ephemeral and unhealthy to overserve — so, better to focus on the former for a long, steady burn and use the latter in strong enough doses to get the fire started. It’s a constant struggle to balance those two variables:

If that group, the cool kids, pulls the ripcord, everyone tends to follow them to the exits. In fact, it’s usually the most high status or desirable people who leave first, the evaporative cooling effect of social networks. At that point, that product or service better have moved as far out as possible on the utility axis or the velocity of churn can cause a nose bleed… eventually, everyone who wants to mine for that social currency will have done so, and most of it will be depleted. At that point, the amount of status-driven potential energy left in the social network flattens. If, at that inflection, the service hasn’t made headway in adding a lot of utility, the network can go stale.

Crucially, I’d add that the more public/visible/transparent the social measuring stick, the more likely it will have a corrosive effect on the network due to unintended consequences like users gaming-the-system. From “The Content Police”:

Goodhart’s Law… observes that, when a measure becomes a target, it ceases to be a good measure… Radical transparency and predictable consistency enable gaming-the-system. If you show bad actors where the line is, they will always toe it (or tip-toe around it). As opaque as its algorithms are, even Google has to play whack-a-mole all day.

Even were that measuring stick to adequately express meritocratic quality, like a strong-form interest graph, it would still likely have a reflexive, Pavlovian effect on behavior. From “The Killer App and the App Killer”:

There’s something really interesting about the distinction between social and interest graphs, especially within context of Instagram’s taxonomy therein. Part of why a killer app for the interest graph has been so elusive is because of how easy the open web’s many layers of abstraction make it to game-the-system.

The point is for entrepreneurs and business strategists to recognize that overindexing to social currency as a means or an end can build a castle made of sand — regardless of whether it’s the right kind (meritocratic quality) or the wrong kind (oligarchic quantity). Perhaps that’s why Wei arranged “utility” as the explanatory variable and “social capital” as the dependent in his 2x2 matrix.

The tradeoff between Proof of Work and market size

For the most part, engineering the perfect conditions to wind-up the “quality is scarcity is value” trinity focuses on the wants and needs of the demand-side. But, two-sided marketplaces like social networks have to match that with equally focused execution on the supply-side too. Here, again, Wei illuminates a difficult balancing act.

To wit, most social networks quickly reach their TAM, because the art and skill of content creation caps the supply side’s upper limit, as discussed by Wei’s “Proof of Work” concept:

Every network has some ceiling on its ultimate number of contributors, and it is often a direct function of its proof of work… a ceiling is a ceiling. If you want to know the terminal value of a network… or what the cap of active users is for any social network, first ask yourself how many people have the skill and interest to compete in that arena.

That means TikTok’s TAM is pretty small because not many people are willing and able to create a dancing lip sync video. As such, Proof of Work is a knife whose barrier-to-entry cuts both ways: It can be beneficial (in the case of engendering the aforementioned scarcity and meritocracy), but also detrimental (as with limiting the potential to scale). Right now, TikTok has to incentivize production and facilitate the consumption thereof, but, longer-term, it will have to innovate to lower the supply-side barriers-to-entry, because an increasingly lopsided producer surplus will mire the network in deadweight loss (DWL). TikTok is a weak social network, but has the potential to be great social media — it’s kind of the opposite of Facebook’s wont.

Tech’s evolution from Web 1.0 (the read web) to Web 2.0 (the write web) massively increased content’s supply side, but even after that supply shock, consumers still out-man producers by a huge margin, per the 1% Rule (aka 1/9/90 Rule):

…only 1% of the users of a website actively create new content, while the other 99% of the participants only lurk… in a collaborative website such as a wiki, 90% of the participants of a community only view content, 9% of the participants edit content, and 1% of the participants actively create new content.

Take Wikipedia, for example, where a plummeting ratio of active-to-registered users may suggest that its proof of work is getting harder and its oligarchs more entrenched. Those are two perilous trends for a crowdsourced network that’s still intent on growth. Wikipedia has 141k registered MAUs out of 35.8M registered users. That’s a skinny 1:254 ratio and it’s getting more lopsided, as the number of active users hasn’t increased despite modest growth in registrations and explosive growth in Wikipedia’s content universe. Thus, a relatively fixed number of active users, like editors, are getting spread increasingly thin while trying to cover an ever-expanding surface area of articles.

At this point, there are no easy solutions there for Wikipedia, to be sure. (At least, none I want to delve into here and now.) Nevertheless, the upshot is that network architects must constantly engineer their systems such that supply meets demand at equilibrium were the network to achieve — and maintain — a desired quantity and quality of liquidity.

Applied theory

At this point, Wei has led the horse to water with a little nudge from me here and there. He’s given us enough to devise and derisk a strategic framework for upstarts who need to gain traction. In fact, his Status-as-a-Service closely resembles a predecessor, “The Prisoner’s Dilemma Wedge”:

Here’s the framework established by that Netflix case study, which anyone can apply via the following canvas…

1. What do you want from upstream suppliers in your industry that will cost these suppliers nothing?

2. Who are the commoditized upstream suppliers in your industry?

3. What’s something you can offer them in exchange for what you want?

4. Who are the end-users in your industry?

5. What is your unique solution?

6. Who are the subset of niche end-users that would pay a premium for your unique solution?

7. What is your value proposition for that subset?

8. Who is the direct competitor in your own horizontal who makes your value proposition look strongest in a head-to-head comparison?

Facebook is the posterchild for StaaS that Wei discusses throughout his piece. So, retrofitting his prototype to The Prisoner’s Dilemma Wedge would yield the following canvas:

Here, I’d add another important editorial tweak of mine. Wei mentions MySpace seven times, and he suggests — in as many words — that its was the direct competitor in Facebook’s horizontal who made the upstart’s value proposition look strongest in a head-to-head comparison (per The Prisoner’s Dilemma Wedge #8 “competition”):

You might wonder, how did Facebook differentiate itself from MySpace? It started out as mostly a bunch of text status updates, nothing necessarily that innovative.

But, I’m not entirely sure MySpace is the correct comp were we to use Facebook as a strategic case study. First off, had TheFacebook targeted MySpace from infancy, then Zuckerberg’s scrappy startup would have comped poorly for end-users who wanted social facilitation (#7 “value proposition”). After all, MySpace had a much bigger network apples-to-apples.

Indeed, there was a second value proposition that Facebook offered: social filtration. Let’s call these two, social facilitation and social filtration, Facebook’s “dual mandate”. Wei himself highlighted both of these as important levers:

Facebook launched with one of the most famous proof of work hurdles in the world: you had to be a student at Harvard. By requiring a harvard.edu email address, Facebook drafted off of one of the most elite cultural filters in the world. It’s hard to think of many more powerful slingshots of elitism. By rolling out, first to Ivy League schools, then to colleges in general, Facebook scaled while maintaining a narrow age dispersion and exclusivity based around educational credentials.

Layer that on top of the broader social status game of stalking attractive members of the other sex that animates much of college life and Facebook was a service that tapped into reserves of some of the most heated social capital competitions in the world.

Yet, MySpace had a competitive advantage in not only the aforementioned facilitation, but also filtration. MySpace served as its own elite cultural filter at the same time that Facebook was scaling. From MySpace’s history:

In August 2003, several eUniverse employees with Friendster accounts saw potential in its social networking features. The group decided to mimic the more popular features of the website. Within 10 days, the first version of Myspace was ready for launch…

The first Myspace users were eUniverse employees. The company held contests to see who could sign up the most users. eUniverse used its 20 million users and e-mail subscribers to breathe life into Myspace, and move it to the head of the pack of social networking websites.

Those 20 million eUniverse users and subscribers delivered celebrities, like musician Tila Tequila, unto MySpace as founding members. That cohort was (and is) more elite, more powerful, more exclusive, and more valuable of a slingshot than Facebook’s own niche subset, Harvard students (#6 in The Prisoner’s Dilemma).

Therefore, if Facebook was at a competitive disadvantage to MySpace across both of its value propositions, then MySpace could not/should not have been its target. It must have been competing against someone or something else, and the Netflix case study provides a hint as to whom or what:

…even in 2008 Starz had a number of on demand offerings of its own, and although every one of them had its own foibles, inertia would’ve likely allowed traditional distributors’ video on demand (VOD) services to squelch Netflix’s offering. But, part of Netflix’s marketing genius was to comp itself not against its own suppliers’ VOD offerings, but rather against Blockbuster and other dinosaur movie rental chains, relative to whom its value proposition was strongest.

That’s the critical insight behind the eighth and final step in The Prisoner’s Dilemma Wedge. Starz was not the direct competitor in Netflix’s horizontal who made the upstart’s value proposition look strongest in a head-to-head comparison. Starz (and others) would have crushed Netflix had they competed directly. Rather, the analog option, Blockbuster, was far easier for Netflix to pick-off.

Rich Barton, founder of both Zillow and Expedia, just discussed this strategy in a recent interview (emphasis mine):

It was always our strategy to bide our time, I can’t remember if you named the process, you’ve been talking a lot about Netflix recently and you’ve always had this strategic intuition that one entry strategy for the disruptor is to come into the industry, bring the casserole to the dinner, come into the house, sit down at the table, be polite, eat, and grow like you’re a baby elephant… you’re growing bigger and bigger and bigger and before you know it you can’t be kicked out of the house. That was my paraphrasing of how you describe the Netflix strategy… And by the way, I did the same thing with Expedia.

Like Netflix, Zillow, and Expedia, Facebook comped poorly against incumbents like MySpace, so Zuckerberg’s traction was oriented around obsoleting analog facebooks — the kind that colleges gave Freshmen in welcome packages on the first day of orientation. Without that insight and its resulting playbook, TheFacebook would have been “kicked out of the house” by MySpace.

Monetizing social status

If StaaS is correct in deducing social currency as carrot and stick for networks gaining traction, then the holy grail for social networks is enabling users to directly convert their social capital to financial capital. Much of Asia has already reached such a steady state, per Wei:

Asia… provides an even cleaner valuation of social capital. There, many social networks allow you to directly turn your social capital into financial capital, without leaving the network [like WeChat and YY]… Meanwhile, on Twitter, if one of your tweets somehow goes massively viral, you still have to attach a follow-up tweet with a link to your GoFundMe page, a vulgar monetization hack in comparison. It’s China, not the U.S., that is the bleeding edge of influencer industrialization.

A number of theoretical and structural barriers-to-entry inhibit American social networks and consumers who are trying to make that leap from dealing social capital to trading financial capital. But, there is a will; there is a way; and I’m excited to tie all of this together in a followup exposé about that next wave…

The archetype

Annotote is a knowledge-based meritocracy where brains are brands and knowledge is power within the network and beyond. It’s the most frictionless way for you to get informed and inform others — an antidote to the information overload — so go check out Annotote:

All signal. No noise. Annotote.

--

--

Anthony Bardaro
Adventures in Consumer Technology

“Perfection is achieved not when there is nothing more to add, but when there is nothing left to take away...” 👉 http://annotote.launchrock.com #NIA #DYODD