General Relationship between Municipal Size and Efficiency

Jie Zhou
Civic Analytics & Urban Intelligence
7 min readSep 24, 2016

Literature Review

A literature review conducted by LUARCC and SPAA in 2008 about optimal size and municipal efficiency discussed the U-shaped curve between municipal size (as measured by population) and expense per capita to deliver municipal services. As is shown in the Figure 1, the U-shape proposes that in the smallest governments, one finds the greatest inefficiency as shown in expenses, that a few gains in proficiency (costs savings) exists as size increments, yet these level off in the center scopes of size, and some inefficiency returns for the largest municipalities. Here the cost per capita measure is an indicator of productivity (rather, the opposite of proficiency, or inefficiency) normally utilized as a part of this sort of examination.

Even this discourse of the (inverted) U-shaped nature of the relationship between size and productivity has variations. This unmistakable articulation is a beginning point: The consensus among researchers who have studied consolidation efforts is that nearly 80 percent of municipal services and activities do not possess economies of scale beyond a population of approximately 20,000 residents.” (Katsuyama, 2003) Gabler utilizes an edge of 25,000 (in 1960 population numbers) and is more vehement about the diseconomies at the substantial end of the scale: “The results of this present study suggest that large cities tend to employ and spend more per capita than the smaller jurisdictions and that this tendency is attributable − in part − to the effects of city size.” (Gabler, 1971) The 1987 report of the Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations, “The Organization of Local Public Economies” gives further backing to these numbers. The report assessed the studies of several researchers and reasoned that per capita costs by and large fall with expanding size for municipalities with populations up to 25,000, remain genuinely consistent for those up to 250,000, yet then ascent essentially.

The U-shaped curve appears to be moderately predictable and generalizable crosswise over social and social connections. A research of water supply in suburb India (World Bank, 2008a) gives more proof of the U-shape, yet for this situation, it is related to families and in an extremely distinctive connection. “The size classes 500 to 1,000 households and 1,000 to 1,500 households have relatively lower cost, compared to smaller or larger piped water supply schemes.” Post-war amalgamation in Japan likewise demonstrated the U-shaped capacity, yet with fairly diverse levels of population, demonstrating 115,109 people was the edge at which proficiency increases would inverse (Mabuchi, 2001).

Figure 1. Hypothesized shape of the relationship between size of jurisdiction and cost of public services

A few studies demonstrate practically little or no relationship between efficiency and size. In a research of counties giving neighborhood services in Iowa (Koven and Hadwiger, 1992), the researchers find no confirmation for the ‘greater is better’ mantra.

The big county is not predominant in many regards. Per capita consumptions of the expansive district surpass those of four of the five small counties. Per capita taxes, also, are higher in the big county functions while were no higher than the per capita costs in smaller ones, with the exception of hospitals, expressways, and capital expenses. The proof from the twofold county shows that economies of scale prompting lower assessments and spending have not happened. Components such as quality of administrations, hierarchical slack, and readiness of inhabitants to pay for administrations must be considered keeping in mind to draw more conclusive inductions concerning the focal points of arrangements for basic rearrangement. The Iowa case above mentioned, however does not back up the perspective that greater is essentially more efficient.

This does not necessarily negate the U-shape bend finding and may bolster it, however the message of the researcher plainly centered around contradicting solidification. Another quote makes that totally clear: “Consolidation may not produce savings or be politically feasible.” Note that capital costs are a special case, which is a point that is obvious in different references.

Australia enacted numerous combinations in light of the board acknowledgment among policy makers that larger municipalities would display more noteworthy economic efficiencies. Byrnes and Dollery (2002) reviewed studies to figure out whether an experimental premise existed for this perspective. Their decision was, “The lack of rigorous evidence of significant economies of scale in municipal service provision casts considerable doubt on using this as the basis for amalgamations.”

An early study from Ontario, Canada discovers little backing for the relationship between size and efficiency, including even among the smallest municipalities (Bodkin and Conklin, 1971). The study was researching the suggestion of solidification advancing efficiency and stated “…our calculations suggest that quite small municipalities, even those with populations in the range of 5,000 to 10,000 persons, can provide fire and police protection, sanitation and waste removal, conservation of health, recreation, and general government services as cheaply, or even more cheaply, than can the larger Municipalities.”

“Sources of Public Service Improvement” (Boyne, 2003) presents a review of empirical researches of public administration execution. It summarizes: “Little support is found as to the proposed relationship between organizational size and service performance.” Generally, numerous variables that acknowledged critical had little or no effect on execution. “There is no indication that extra resources (financial & real resources) lead to poorer services, and there is only moderate support for the proposition that it will lead to better services.” On one element, the author offers a positive go-ahead: administrative variables have a noteworthy impact on execution performance. Here we discuss the administration further under categories of efficiency.

In spite of the fact that the focus of Mera’s article, “On the Urban Agglomeration and Economic Efficiency” (Mera, 1973), is economic advancement, there is an unmistakable explanation from the proof that identifies with government consumptions per capita:

The evidence supported the proposition that wealth or resources (measured in terms of median family income and state aid) is far more important than population size or density in explaining variations in total per capita expenditures among local units…This conclusion is not unique; it confirms earlier studies which tend to show that the expenditure per capita is not very much related to the population size when the expenditure is one way or another adjusted for quality differences.

The study, “Fragmentation and Sprawl: Evidence from Interregional Analysis” (Carruthers and Ulfarrson, 2002), that concentrated on the relationship between sprawl and fragmentation also takes notes of the impact on public expenses. “Fragmentation is associated with lower densities and higher property values but has no direct effect on public service expenditures.”

Conclusions

• The Inverted U-shaped Curve

There is a transformed U-formed relationship between size and efficiency on a general level. Efficiency rises with population size up to around 25,000 individuals, and thereafter it is steady until size is around 250,000 individuals, while it declines with expanding population size after that. The inverted U-shaped curve that portrays the relationship between city size and efficiency offers two open doors for improvement: the exceptionally smallest and the exceptionally largest governments. The literature characterizes the smallest as populations under 20,000 to 25,000. The largest are regions with populations in overabundance of 250,000, which is a restricted pool in New Jersey. Nevertheless, in one reference from the writing seek that particularly concentrated New Jersey (Gabler, 1969), the diseconomy at the largest end of the range was more consistently purported than in two other states to which it was compared. The literature recommends New Jersey ought to inspect its largest governments as well as its smallest governments for approaches to improve efficiencies.

• Service Specific Relationships

The most critical finding other than the upset U-shaped curve was the contrast in the relationship between size and efficiency in capital based administrations rather than work-escalated administrations. Efficiency increases are identified with size for capital or infrastructure condensed administrations such as sewer and water. The study supports the findings that this same idea is operative for seldom utilized and specialize administrations, for example, a high innovation technology crime lab. This proposes contracting, sharing, or getting specialized administrations from a bigger entity can make chosen services more efficient.

• Labor-Intensive Services

Work-escalated administrations are more productive in smaller governments. The literature only provides burdens of management control and excess administration in bigger governments as a clarification for such inefficiencies. Diminished levels of administrations and expectations in smaller towns may likewise be operated to decrease costs. This finding of increased efficiency in smaller units is an essential conclusion, on the grounds that the study traits more than 80 percent of administrative expense to work concentrated administrations including education, police and fire.

• Complexity of Measuring Efficiency

An extra finding is the difficulty in deciding one measure of efficiency that functions well at a municipality level or even for an administration area. The most well-known premise for an estimation of efficiency is expenditure data, which is the numerator in the expense per capita. The culprit in the comparability of this indicator is varying definitions of expenditure measures across jurisdictions. LUARCC has started to assess the likelihood of utilizing civil expenditure data information in New Jersey to analyze efficiency and the factors that advance it. While a troublesome task, this makes much sense, in view of the capacity to endeavor to control a portion of the confounding impacts.

--

--