On Bonding Curves as Funding Mechanisms

Approaches for extracting funds from bonding curves

Wilson Lau
Thoughtchains
Published in
7 min readSep 15, 2018

--

Currently, most token bonding curve models require that money in = money out. This model is very attractive for a wide range of applications, as the core promise is to incentivize participation, and early participants will potentially reap financial gains for their early commitments to a project.

However, while these curves can incentivize participation, they are not designed to actually fund projects; the amount bonded is effectively locked in. I can imagine that there are many applications where funding would benefit supporters of a project by enabling development, marketing, or whatnot — so we’re left with a question: How might we use bonding curves to fund projects?

Background

In my last article on single bonding curves for continuous token models, I alluded to

’s initial writing on bonding curves that proposed a two-curve model where the buy price is different from the sell price. This article explores the use of this type of ‘two-curve model’ for fundraising.

also recently published a piece on how to create revenue for members of TCRs (that use a bonding curve). In summary, he suggests a mechanism for allowing individuals / companies to donate to the curve without receiving any tokens, which would increase value for all of the token holders. This article actually explores the exact opposite process.

I generally also believe that the projects underlying bonding curves can be revenue-generating in addition to having this capital gain opportunity. I believe that that revenue should be distributed to token holders pari passu regardless of the price at which they purchased the token. This article alludes to revenue-generating projects funded by bonding curves.

I also refer to the equation I designed in my previous article a few times here, so I’ve copied it here as a reference:

where a represents the precentage growth in price per factor-increase, b is a constant that adjusts the functions in the spirit of y = mx + b, c is the base of the factor-increase (ex. 2 for a doubling), and m is a multiplicative factor that adjusts the ‘slope’ of the curve defined.

Funding Mechanisms for Single Bonding Curves

1. Redemption Limits

The simplest means of securing capital for a bonding curve is to set a redemption limit. Effectively, the last X tokens go to 0.

This is a bet on the curve being sustained over an indefinite period of time, and that at no point in time does the project expect its tokens to be fully redeemed. Therefore, an amount of capital can be safely removed from the system without major consequences.

This trades off the ability to guarantee the fully redeemed amount for some amoutn of capital while preserving a lot of the core characteristics of the bonding curve. This is what it would probably look like:

Ideally, the token holders would vote to ramp up this redemption limit over time relative to the total amount bonded. In my view, this amount should represent a fairly insignificant amount of the total amount bonded, but those with greater risk appetites may disagree. The caution is that setting a redemption limit unwisely could spur FUD and lead to a ‘bank run’ of sorts on the bonding curve.

2. Discounting Curves

Projects can also raise a target amount of money by discounting the curve over a range of tokens already distributed. The target amount can then be removed from the bonding curve and be used to fund projects. Effectively, this is a project’s bet that discounting the curve now to invest in the project will lead to more participation or revenue in the future. Individual token holders be incentivized by the price going up with more participation, and not necessarily the shape of the curve.

This involves calculating the target amount, and then changing a number of variables on the curve (lowering m/a, increasing c). Here’s a diagram to illustrate how it might work:

3. Staking / Loans

Upon the release of Casper PoS on Ethereum, ETH can be staked and will receive interest / mining fees of some percentage. If we can build a mechanism for staking the ETH committed to a bonding curve, cash flow can be generated for the project in a way that is very similar to an endowment. Managing this may be difficult due to withdrawal delays, but I would hope that emerging staking pools like RocketPool may offer a good solution to make this easy and limit the issue of withdrawal delays.

Alternatively, there is potential to issue debt-like instruments so that the staked amounts can earn interest. The challenge will be in the automated, well-governed management of the bonded funds. Integrating with a project like Dharma may make sense here.

I find this concept especially interesting, largely because it combines characteristics of an endowment — an ability to fund development or other initiatives over a long period of time— with an underlying bonding curve that allows individuals to reap capital gains for their early commitment to the project, and potentially even ongoing cash flow if the underlying project is revenue-generating. The challenge is that debt-like returns means that a lot of capital would required to fund any meaningful work.

Funding Mechanisms for Double Bonding Curves

In

’s initial article, he proposes two options: one where buy price > sell price, and vice versa. I cannot think of a way that a curve where sell price > buy price could possibly exist without immediate abuse, but a curve where buy price > sell price is very useful.

Where buy price > sell price, the delta between the two curves can be withdrawn from the contract safely and be used to fund the project underlying the bonding curve.

Looking at the options

There are effectively three categories for how the delta between these curves can be designed — one where the two curves converge, diverge, or remain consistently divergent. Each has slightly different outcomes:

An increasly divergent set of curves will continue to create more and more excess ‘delta’ that can be withdrawn from the curve. The relative difference between the two curves can remain consistent (for example, a 10% discount), but the absolute difference will continue to grow. A curve where relative difference is growing would be unadvisable simply because contributors will be taking increasingly large losses to even participate.

These curves can simply be designed by creating a base curve, and then applying a discount (m) to create the selling curve. I think this is a viable model, as it is not uncommon to immediately take a predictable loss for future potential. The project can then be funded with 10% of all total contributions made.

A consistently divergent set of curves acts fairly similarly to the divergent set of curves. Instead of taking a percentage discount, participants take a discount of absolute value (0.1 ETH) when they make a contribution. The project can then be funded with discount * number of contributions made.

This curve can also be simply designed by starting with a base curve, and then applying a negative vertical transformation (-b) to the first equation.

Lastly, a convergent set of curves allows for a target amount to be raised over a a raise of tokens issued, but ultimately converge and act like a single bonding curve after the target amount is raised. This is ideal for a project that needs a bit of capital to get started, but is unlikely to need any excess funds past that.

Further Thoughts

Double Contributions

With these double bonding curve models, it is important to note that the amount contributed will be based on the number of individual transactions on the curve, and not the total amount bonded. This is important for keeping track of how much excess capital has been contributed to the curve.

Every time someone sells back to the curve, they create an opportunity for a new contributor to make the same transaction again over the same range of the curve. This means that the total amount of excess capital available is not simply the difference between the two curves, but a function of the number of token purchases made on the curve.

Reusability of Funding Mechanisms

Most of these mechanisms are reusable and allow for multiple ‘rounds’ of fundraising if necessary as the project grows. Creating the flexibility in the contracts to allow for these variables to keep changing over time will give projects the flexibility to rely on these mechanisms again and again.

Governance

As I describe more and more of these mechanisms, I recognize the need for better governance in these structures as they get more complicated. Not only do the contracts need to have the flexibility to be manipulated, but projects need to think about how they will managing the voting and governance process for making changes to these curves.

Thank you for reading! I think these mechanisms offer a very interesting alternative to the ever-popular ICO model that is much more conducive to community-driven development and projects.

A lot of people have reached out to chat with me about bonding curves, and I am also happy to help out with the design of any of these projects and to see some of these ideas come to life. You can find me at hello@wilsonplau.com.

I am of course open to any and all feedback you might have these ideas as we’re still in the very early stages of this whole ecosystem, and it’s been an amazing experience learning from everyone so far.

--

--

Wilson Lau
Thoughtchains

Software Engineer at Mercari, Entrepreneur and Indie Hacker. Based in Tokyo. www.wilsonplau.com